Paul Krugman’s Economic Blinders
Michael
Hudson
Paul Krugman is widely appreciated
for his New York Times columns
criticizing Republican demands for fiscal austerity. He rightly argues that
cutting back public spending will worsen the economic depression into which we
are sinking. And despite his partisan Democratic Party politicking, he warned
from the outset in 2009 that President Obama’s modest counter-cyclical spending
program was not sufficiently bold to spur recovery.
These are the themes of his new
book, End This Depression Now. In
old-fashioned Keynesian style he believes that the solution to insufficient
market demand is for the government to run larger budget deficits. It should
start by giving revenue-sharing grants of $300 billion annually to states and
localities whose budgets are being squeezed by the decline in property taxes
and the general economic slowdown.
All this is a good idea as far as it
goes. But Mr. Krugman stops there – as if that is all that is needed today. So what he has done is basically get into
a fight with intellectual pygmies. Thus dumbs down his argument, and actually
distracts attention from what is needed to avoid the financial and fiscal
depression he is warning about.
Here’s the problem: To focus the
argument against “Austerian” advocates of fiscal balance, Mr. Krugman hopes
that economists will stop distracting attention by talking about what he deems not necessary. It seems not necessary to write down debts, for
example. All that is needed is to reduce interest rates on existing debts,
enabling them to be carried.
Mr.
Krugman also does not advocate shifting taxes off labor onto property. The
implication is that California can afford its Proposition #13 – the tax freeze
on commercial property and homes at long-ago levels, which has fiscally
strangled the state and led to an explosion of debt-leveraged housing prices by
leaving the site value untaxed and hence free to be pledged to banks for larger
and larger mortgage loans instead of being paid to the public authorities.
There is hint in Mr. Krugman’s journalism of a need to reverse the tax shift
off real estate and finance (onto income and sales taxes), except to restore a
bit more progressive taxation.
The
effect of Mr. Krugman’s suggestions is for the government to subsidize the
existing financial and tax structures, leaving the debts intact and
ignoring the largely regressive, unfair and inefficient system of taxation. It
is unfair because the profits of the rich – and even worse, their asset-price
(“capital”) gains are taxed at lower rates and riddled with tax loopholes and
giveaways. The wealthy benefit from the public infrastructure being advocated
by Mr. Krugman, but there is not a word about their being taxed. The government
provides public benefits (such as state sponsored health insurance for which
Walmart employees are eligible as a result of their near-starvation wages).
So
it is important to note what Mr. Krugman does not address these issues that
once played so important a role in Democratic Party politics, before the Wall
Street faction gained control via the campaign financing process – even before
the Citizens United case. For over a century, economists have recognized the
need for financial and fiscal reform to go together. Failure to proceed with a
joint reform has led the banking and financial sector – along with its major
client base, the real estate sector – to capture the tax system and channel easy
credit to the banks – to relend to governments and load the economy at large
down with debt.
In
Mr. Krugman’s reading these debts need not be written down or the tax
system made more efficient. It is to be better subsidized – mainly with easier
bank credit and more government spending. So I am afraid that his book might as
well have been subtitled “How the Economy can Borrow its Way Out of Debt.” That
is what budget deficits do: they add to the debt overhead. And by doing so,
they transfer wealth from the public trust to the bondholders (and their
descendants) who receive interest payments on government bonds – especially
where (as in Europe ) no central bank is permitted
simply to monetize the deficit spending.
Mr. Krugman has become censorial
regarding the debt issue over the last month or so. In last Friday’s New York Times column he wrote: “Every
time some self-important politician or pundit starts going on about how
deficits are a burden on the next generation, remember that the biggest problem
facing young Americans today isn’t the future burden of debt.”[1]
Unfortunately, Mr. Krugman’s failure to see today’s economic problem as one of
debt deflation reflects his failure (suffered by most economists, to be sure)
to recognize the need for debt writedowns, for restructuring the banking and
financial system, and for shifting taxes off labor back onto property, economic
rent and asset-price (“capital”) gains. The effect of his narrow set of
recommendations is to defend the status quo – and for my money, despite his
reputation as a liberal, that makes Mr. Krugman a conservative. I see little in
his logic that would oppose Rubinomics, which has remained the Democratic
Party’s program under the Obama administration.
Many
of Mr. Krugman’s readers find him the leading hope of opposing even worse
Republican politics. But what can be worse than the Rubinomics that Larry
Summers, Tim Geithner, Rahm Emanuel and other Wall Street holdovers from the
Democratic Leadership Committee have embraced?
Perhaps I can prod Mr. Krugman into
taking a stronger position on this issue. But what worries me is that he has
moved sharply to the “Rubinomics” wing of his party. He insists that debt
doesn’t matter. Bank fraud, junk mortgages and casino capitalism are not the
problem, or at least not so serious that more deficit spending cannot cure it.
Criticizing Republicans for emphasizing structural unemployment, he writes: “authoritative-sounding
figures insist that our problems are ‘structural,’ that they can’t be fixed
quickly. … What does it mean to say that we have a structural unemployment
problem? The usual version involves the claim that American workers are stuck
in the wrong industries or with the wrong skills.”[2]
Using neoclassical sleight-of-hand
to bait and switch, he narrows the meaning of “structural reform” to refer to Chicago School economists
who blame today’s unemployment as being “structural,” in the sense of workers
trained for the wrong jobs. This diverts the reader’s attention away from the
pressing problems that are genuinely
structural.
The word “structural” refers to the
systemic imbalances that neoclassical economists dismiss as “institutional”:
the debt overhead, the legal system – especially unfair and dysfunctional
bankruptcy and foreclosure laws, regulations against financial fraud, and
wealth distribution in general. In 1979, for example, I juxtaposed economic
structuralism to Chicago School monetarism
in my monograph on Canada in the New Monetary Order. I have elaborated that discussion
my textbook on Trade, Development and
Foreign Debt (new ed. 2010). The tradition is grounded in the Progressive
Era’s reform program. Correcting such structural and institutional defects,
parasitism and privilege seeking “free lunches” is what classical political
economy was all about – and what the neoclassical reaction sought to exclude
from the economic curriculum. But from the perspective of neoclassical writers
through Rubinomics deregulators, the problem of massive, unpayably high debt
expanding inexorably by compound interest (and penalty fees) simply disappears.
So the great problem today is
whether to stop the siphoning off of income and wealth to financial
institutions at the top of the economic pyramid, or reverse the polarization
that has taken place over the past thirty years between creditors and debtors,
financial institutions and the rest of the economy. I realize that it is more
difficult to criticize someone for an error of omission than for an error of commission. But the distinction was
erased a month ago when Mr. Krugman got lost in the black hole of banking,
finance and international trade theory that has engulfed so many neoclassical
and old-style Keynesian economists. But last month Mr. Krugman insisted that
banks do not create credit, except by borrowing reserves that (in his view)
merely shifts lending savings from wealthy people to those with a higher
propensity to consume. Criticizing Steve Keen, who has just published a second
edition of his excellent Debunking
Economics to explain the dynamics of endogenous money creation, he wrote:
Keen then goes on to assert that lending is, by
definition (at least as I understand it), an addition to aggregate demand. I
guess I don’t get that at all. If I decide to cut back on my spending and stash
the funds in a bank, which lends them out to someone else, this doesn’t have to
represent a net increase in demand. Yes, in some (many) cases lending is
associated with higher demand, because resources are being transferred to
people with a higher propensity to spend; but Keen seems to be saying something
else, and I’m not sure what. I think it has something to do with the notion
that creating money = creating demand, but again that isn’t right in any model
I understand.
Keen
says that it’s because once you include banks, lending increases the money
supply. OK, but why does that matter? He seems to assume that aggregate demand
can’t increase unless the money supply rises, but that’s only true if the
velocity of money is fixed;[3]
But
“velocity” is just a dummy variable to “balance” any given equation – a
tautology, not an analytic tool. As a neoclassical economist, Mr. Krugman is
unwilling to acknowledge that banks not only create credit; in doing so, they create debt. That is
the essence of balance sheet accounting. But writing like a tyro, Mr. Krugman
offers the mythology of banks that can only lend out money taken in from
depositors (as though these banks were good old-fashioned savings banks or
S&Ls, not what Mr. Keen calls “endogenous money creators”). As writers from
J.K. Galbraith to Ellen Brown and Stephen Zarlenga have popularized, banks lend
money that they do not have by creating “credit” in the form of an electronic
entry.
Mr.
Krugman then doubled down on his assertion that bank debt creation doesn’t
matter. People decide how much income they want to save, or decide how much to
borrow to buy goods that their stagnant wage levels no longer enable them to
afford. Everything is a matter of choice,
not a necessity (“price-inelastic” is
the neoclassical euphemism):
First
of all, any individual bank does, in fact, have to lend out the money it
receives in deposits. Bank loan officers can’t just issue checks out of thin
air; like employees of any financial intermediary, they must buy assets with
funds they have on hand.
So
how much currency does the public choose to hold, as opposed to stashing funds
in bank deposits? Well, that’s an economic decision, which responds to things
like income, prices, interest rates, etc.. In other words, we’re firmly back in
the domain of ordinary economics, in which decisions get made at the margin and
all that. Banks are important, but they don’t take us into an alternative
economic universe.
As I read various stuff on banking — comments here, but also various writings here and there — I often see the view that banks can create credit out of thin air. There are vehement denials of the proposition that banks’ lending is limited by their deposits, or that the monetary base plays any important role; banks, we’re told, hold hardly any reserves (which is true), so the Fed’s creation or destruction of reserves has no effect.[4]
As I read various stuff on banking — comments here, but also various writings here and there — I often see the view that banks can create credit out of thin air. There are vehement denials of the proposition that banks’ lending is limited by their deposits, or that the monetary base plays any important role; banks, we’re told, hold hardly any reserves (which is true), so the Fed’s creation or destruction of reserves has no effect.[4]
Not only do banks create new credit – debt, from the
vantage point of their customers – but this new debt creation is the only way
that the economy has avoided a sharp shrinking of consumption and downgrading
of labor. The banks offer is one most people can’t refuse: “Take out a mortgage
or go without a home,” or “Take out a student loan or go without an education
and try to get a job at McDonald’s.” In other words, “Your money or your life.”
It is what banks have been saying through the ages. The difference is that they
can now create credit freely – and as Alan Greenspan has pointed out to Senate
committees, workers are so debt-burdened (“one check away from homelessness”)
that they are afraid that if they complain about working conditions, ask for
higher salaries (to say nothing of trying to unionize), they will be fired. If
they miss a paycheck their credit-card rates will soar to about 29%. And if
they miss a mortgage payment, they may face foreclosure and lose their home. So
the banking system has cowed the population with its credit- and debt-creating
power.
Mr. Krugman’s blind spot with regard
to the debt overhead derails trade theory as well. If Greece leaves the
Eurozone and devalues its currency (the drachma), for example, debts
denominated in euros or other hard currency will rise proportionally. So Greece cannot
leave without repudiating its debts in today’s litigious global economy. Yet
Mr. Krugman believes in the old neoclassical nonsense that all that is needed
is “devaluation” to lower the cost of domestic labor. It is as if he is
indifferent to the suffering that such austerity imposes – as Latin American
countries suffered at the hands of IMF austerity plans from the 1970s onward. Costs can “be brought in line by adjusting exchange rates.”[5]
The problem thus is simply one of exchange rates (which translates into labor
costs in short order). Currency depreciation will (in Mr. Krugman’s trade
theory) reduce labor’s cost and other domestic costs to the point where
governments can export enough not only to cover their imports, but to pay their
foreign-currency debts (which will soar in depreciated local-currency terms).
If this were the case, Germany
could have paid its reparations debt by depreciating the mark in 1921. But it
did so by a billion-fold, even this did not suffice to pay. Neither
neoclassical trade theorists nor Chicago School monetarists get
the fact that when public or private debts are denominated in a foreign (hard)
currency, devaluation devastates the economy. The past half-century has shown this
again and again (most recently in Iceland ).
Domestic assets are transferred into foreign hands – including those of
domestic oligarchies operating out of their offshore dollar or Swiss-franc
accounts.
Blindness to the debt issue results
in especial nonsense when applied to analysis of why the U.S. economy
has lost its export competitiveness. How on earth can American industry be
expected to compete when employees must pay about 40 percent of their wages on
debt-leveraged housing, about 10 percent more on student loans, credit cards
and other bank debt, 15 percent on FICA, and about 10 to 15 percent more in
income and sales taxes? Between 75 and 80 percent of the wage payment is
absorbed by the Finance, Insurance and Real Estate (FIRE ) sector
even before employees can start buying goods and services! No wonder the
economy is shrinking, sales are falling off, and new investment and hiring have
followed suit.
How will the government running a
larger deficit cope with today’s dimension of the debt problem – except to
enable states and localities to spend marginally more revenue and avoid further
layoffs, while the military industrial complex steps up its “Pentagon
capitalism”?
Increasing the debt burden of
European nations has the same dire consequences. Germany balks at
bailing out Greece un less Greece moves to
streamline its bloated government and inefficient bureaucracy, stop tax evasion
by the wealthy, clean up corruption and, in a word, be more Germanic. The U.S.
“Austerian” budget cutters whom Mr. Krugman criticizes likewise can point to
wasteful government spending, failing to distinguish positive infrastructure
investment from pork-barrel “roads to nowhere” and tax loopholes promoted by
Congressional politicians whose campaigns are sponsored by special financial
interests, real estate and monopolies.
But I fear that Mr. Krugman is being
drawn into the gravitational pull of Rubinomics, the Democratic Party’s black
hole from which the light of clarity dealing with the debt issue and bad
financial and legal structures simply cannot escape. The only variables he
admits are structure-free: The federal government can spend more, and interest
rates can be lowered (especially on mortgages) so that the higher debt overhead
can be afforded more easily. No need to write it down. That seemingly obvious
and sensible structural solution seems too extreme to Mr. Krugman simply
because it lies outside the scope of his neoclassical economics. He fails to
recognize that debts that can’t be paid, won’t be. This is the immediate
problem facing the U.S. and
European economies today – and the way in which it is resolved will shape the
coming generation.
The problem with Mr. Krugman’s
analysis is that bank debt creation plays no analytic role in Mr. Krugman’s
proposals to rescue the economy. It is as if the economy operates without
wealth or debt, simply on the basis of spending power flowing into the economy
from the government, and being spent on consumer goods, investment goods and
taxes – not on debt service, pension fund set-asides or asset price inflation.
If the government will spend enough – run up a large enough deficit to pump
money into the spending stream, Keynesian-style – the economy can revive by
enough to “earn its way out of debt.”
Such unreal fantasies are the result
of limits and intellectual blinders imposed by neoclassical economics. It
brainwashes students to treat all activity as current spending and consumption. Debt is left out of account.
Without
recognizing the role of debt, one cannot see that what is preventing American
industry from exporting more is the heavy debt overhead that diverts income to
pay Finance, Insurance and Real Estate (FIRE )
expenditures. How can U.S. labor compete with foreign labor when employees and
their employers are obliged to pay such high mortgage debt for its housing,
such high student debt for its education, such high medical insurance and
Social Security (FICA withholding), such high credit-card debt – all this even
before spending on goods and services?
In
fact, how can wage earners even afford to buy what they produce? The problem
interfering with the circular flow between producers and consumers (“Say’s
Law”) is not “saving” as such. It is debt payment. And unless debts are written
down, the U.S. economy
will shrink just as will the economies of Greece , Spain , Portugal , Italy , Ireland , Iceland and other
countries subjected to the Washington Consensus of neoliberal austerity.
Michael
Hudson’s new book summarizing his economic theories, “The Bubble and Beyond,”
will be available in a few weeks on Amazon.
No comments:
Post a Comment